Thursday, February 10, 2011

A marriage made in hell: Big Govt and Big Business

Adam Smith recognized 200+ years ago that big business wasn't a natural supporter of free markets.  Big business is for anything it can do to get government to protect its own selfish interests.  if that means lots of regulations, then so be it.  When government tries to intervene to fix the market, it opens itself up to becoming hijacked by special interests of Big Business (and organized labor).  in this way, government regulation aimed at fixing the market is ultimately self defeating.  the very government that wants to fix the market is open to being co opted by the market players that aim to rig the game in their favor.  The best way to level the playing field isn't for government to inject enlightened regulations every where.  it is for the government to protect private property rights and free exchange.  only then will the little guy have a chance.   

this article by David Reilly in today's WSJ underscores why Big Finance is for Big Government.  

Wall Street Hearts Socialized Housing

America's bastion of capitalism can't get enough of government support. What Wall Street really cares about when it comes to the Obama administration's housing-finance proposals, expected Friday, is that Uncle Sam continues to guarantee the bulk of the country's new mortgages.

The rest is just details. Important ones, to be sure, especially as they relate to the shape and size of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac, as well as the cost of mortgages. But the central question revolves around whether government should explicitly back mortgages.

Sadly, the administration's proposals aren't likely to tackle that issue head on, even if they are painted as long-term moves to wind down Fannie and Freddie. The ostensible reason is that any transition away from government support, unless taken super slow, would further depress housing and choke off the economic recovery. Currently, Fannie, Freddie and agencies like the Federal Housing Administration guarantee more than 90% of all new mortgages.

But there is a deeper reluctance to upset the postcrisis status quo. Markets favor a world in which government takes on most, if not all, mortgage credit risk while investors deal only with things like interest-rate risk. While there is much ire directed at Fannie and Freddie, "many groups benefited from the existing system and want to see a version of it remain," Jaret Seiberg, an analyst at MF Global, noted in a report this week.

For taxpayers, however, this makes little sense. They get stuck with a potentially huge bill while supporting investors who should be in the business of assessing credit risk. If changing that means mortgages grow more expensive over time, it would at least remove the temptation for politicians to use mortgages as an instrument of policy and ensure that house prices remain more in line with fundamentals. The trouble is, without a hard deadline for change, even if years out, markets will likely defeat any attempt to remove guarantees.
So what will the administration propose? The Treasury Department is expected to put forward three proposals, one in which the government would exit from the housing-finance market, another in which there is more limited involvement and a third that more closely mirrors the current backing afforded through Fannie and Freddie. But this isn't likely to result in any drastic change to the overarching structure of mortgage markets for some time, notes FTN analyst Jim Vogel.

Granted, there may be incremental changes. Analysts at Goldman Sachs say these could include efforts to reduce the size of loans that can be backed by Fannie and Freddie, reduce the size of the mortgage giants' balance sheets and increase the fees they charge to guarantee mortgages.

Those are all good steps. But without a long-term commitment to stop subsidizing and distorting housing markets, they will fall short.
Write to David Reilly at david.reilly@wsj.com

grep ip epitomizes upside down thinking of inflation targeting orthodoxy

Greg Ip used to be point guy on Fed coverage for WSJ.  he is now head of US economy desk at the Economist Magazine.   he is very smart guy.   I met him last July as part of a US-focused research agenda I organized for group of our institutional investor clients (1 day in NYC, 2 days in DC).   IT was clear from our meeting with him that he is fully invested in the conventional, mainstream inflation targeting model.   i think this model is fatally flawed, but i still ended up following  Greg's writings and blog posting for the Economist because he writes well and covers interesting topics.  see recent commentary on jobs report in article titled "Where are the Jobs: Troubling trends behind the Falling unemployment rate" at following link:  http://www.economist.com/node/18114537/print

What i want to talk about here is Greg’s recent blog post which I’ve copied below along with my comments I've added to his article in RED.  my main point is this:  Greg's blog post epitomizes the upside down thinking that is forced upon us when we use the conventional mainstream model using CPI as proxy for inflation.   Ip is worried about making policy mistakes if we don’t understand various key points he highlights in his piece.  What he completely ignores is “the fact” that inflation targeting is what got us into the mess we are currently in.   

Inflation lessons from the Asian crisis
Feb 9th 2011, 23:01 by G.I. | WASHINGTON
FOR those convinced that America is on the verge of becoming Weimar Germany, the high price of oil and gold are exhibits one and two. Often forgotten is the fact that both are traded in global markets and reflect global, not American, demand. Failing to appreciate the distinction can lead to policy mistakes. Just look at 1998.   Gold and oil are traded globally but when they are priced in USD, their price reflects USD currency debasement. Further it is critical to keep in mind that global demand for gold and oil is ultimately determined by Fed policy – especially in Asia because the Asia bloc is essentially pegged to USD, which means Asian monetary policy is by default Fed policy.  the boom in EM is a result of easy Fed policy, which shows up in surge in FX reserves.  FX reserves are high powered money!  When the Fed prints money, the money shows up in Asian central banks, which ultimately means the Fed is literally injecting high powered money into these economies.
A financial crisis tipped east Asia into a deep recession in 1997-98, which spread to Russia and then the United States via Long Term Capital Management. To cushion the spillover to America, the Fed first aborted a nascent monetary tightening cycle, then actually cut interest rates. It could do so in part because collapsing Asian demand crushed the price of oil, sending headline inflation below 2%.  This was beginning of the Greenspan put.  As long as CPI was considered low, the Fed had green light to temporarily flood markets with liquidity, which is what it did following collapse of LTCM.    i emphasize the word "temporary" here because ultimately USD conditions kept getting tighter through 2001 as evidenced in gold price which kept declining through 2001 when it hit low of $260.
We now know that between cheaper oil and the Fed’s rate cuts, the Asian crisis was ultimately a positive for an economy already operating below 5% unemployment. Growth, and with it the stock market, went into overdrive. The result was the Nasdaq bubble.  This is one narrative.  Another narrative based on the gold price is this:  the Fed accommodated global liquidity tightening beginning in 1996 coincident with Greenspans irrational exuberance speech.  Tight global liquidity literally triggered the Asian crisis by tightening access to liquidity for over-leveraged Asian borrowers, such as Finance One in Thailand.

The surprise demise of Finance One in Thailand led to panic capital flight and forced lending calls by foreign lenders who worried that other Asian credits would default.  It is no coincidence the Asia Crisis followed close on heals of gold price peaking in 2006 and declining into Greenspan's well documented / infamous concerns about a nascent equity bubble in the US. 

My alternative "gold price" narrative is this:  the Fed triggered the Asian crisis by either actively or passively draining dollar liquidity from markets.  Greenspan was worried about equity bubble in the US and therefore he welcomed USD deflation!  The Fed cut interest rates following collapse of LTCM, but monetary conditions remained tight from 1997 to 2000 as reflected in declining commodity and gold prices. 

Tight USD money conditions actied to exacerbate the tech bubble by encouraging inflows into non-physical tech related internet stocks as physical assets deflated in value thanks to USD deflation.    The difference between the Great Recession of 2008 and the post tech bubble bursting environment is that the tech bubble burst into a five year global deflation cycle!!!  the Fed could thus reflate / debase USD with impunity.   

Micro vs Macro bubbles and Systemic Risk
The tech bubble was what I would call a “micro” bubble.   it wasn’t a result of easy money; in fact it was paradoxically the case that tech stocks benefited from deflationary money conditions as evidenced by declining price of commodities and gold during period from 1996 to 2000.  Who wanted to put money into natural resource stocks during this 1997-2000 period?   The tech bubble wiped out more wealth than the sub prime crisis, yet sub prime was ultimately a “systemic” crisis because it was coincident with an economy wide bubble fueled by easy money (clearly evidenced in gold price boom from $260 in 2001 to $900 in 2008 ahead of Lehman collapse). 

There was only short recession following dot com bust and no systemic implications because we were starting from point of low point of global deflation.  Today we are in a very different situation.  The sub prime bust came on top of a global inflation!!!  thus, when the Fed reflated into the bust it built another inflation on top of the previous one.  that is where we are now.  The Fed could reflate the economy with impunity following the dot com bust with an ultra low interest rate cycle because our starting point was a period of prolonged global deflation.  The dot come bubble was a micro Asset bubble.  the Great Recession resulted from a "macro" easy money bubble.
Today, we have the mirror image. Surging demand in emerging markets that are at or near capacity has driven up commodity prices at a time when America is awash in unused capacity. Buying gold as an inflation hedge makes a lot of sense, if you live in China or India.
Buying gold makes sense in USD because the USD price of gold is surging because the Fed is printing easy money – and money demand remains depressed.  This is double whammy for fueling USD global liquidity – surging money supply and weak money demand.

Just as the plunge in the price of oil in 1998 did not signal deflationary pressure in America  WHAT ARE YOU KIDDING ME GREG?!? the oil plunge was directly related to global ongoing USD deflation as expressed in falling gold price , its rise today does not signal inflationary pressure here, unless it works its way into expectations and wages, of which there’s no sign yet. (The 0.4% rise in hourly wages in January looks weird; for now, I’d discount it.)   This statement may be technically true but it rests on erroneous definition of inflation as a rise in the general price level. 
In fact, it could do the opposite: by draining more American purchasing power to overseas suppliers, higher oil prices leave less money to spend on stuff made in America. (America is a net food exporter so higher food prices are positive for American growth.) If the Fed were to tighten monetary policy today in response to Asia’s inflation problem, it could be the opposite of the mistake it made in 1998, compounding a deflationary shock at a time when the economy is significantly below potential.
Worrying about stabilizing CPI has us chasing our tails.  We need a sound money policy.   the Fed’s attempt to peg a certain stable price level is counter productive and dangerous.    Relatively stable CPI inflation is the result of stable macro dynamics, not the cause.    CPI should be allowed to rise and fall depending on productivity shocks.  If productivity is high, then CPI would naturally be falling.  To keep CPI artificially above zero with easy money policy is to sow seeds of credit boom bust cycle like we saw in 2005-2007. 


The Inflation Train is Here (Again)!

Robert Murphy is my favorite contemporary Austrian Economist.  See his short article copied below titled: Investors Finally Fear the Inflation Precipice. It is no coincidence Murphy calls himself a “proud member of the fuddy duddies who have predicted return to serious stagflation.”  Count me one too.  The Murphy article triggered the following reflections….

Einstein said "We can't solve problems by using the same kind of thinking we used when we created them."  Conventional mainstream economics got us into this mess; it won’t get us out.  Why I prefer the Austrian framework is because I believe it allows us to see problems before convention mainstream economics is capable of seeing them. 

This is because the conventional model is focused primarily on the consumer price index as a key anchor for macro economic stability.  As long as CPI is stable, we are supposed to assume the economy is stable.  The Fed takes it one step further.  It claims that if it maintains stable, low CPI it will ensure macro stability.   This is circular logic.   

According to the Austrian school model, inflation is not the CPI.  CPI is the tail of the inflation dog.  CPI is the result of inflation, it isn’t the thing itself.   Inflation is credit expansion; inflation is a debasement of the currency.  Currency debasement is easily measurable via the gold price.  When the gold price goes up, we know there is “inflation.”  it really is that simple. 

History has now proven in two painful episodes how silly the claim is by mainstream economics that stable CPI leads to stable macro performance.  We have the Great Depression and in the latest 2007/8 crisis as living proof of the folly of pegging monetary policy to the CPI. In the 1920s we pegged to WPI, but the idea was basically the same back then.  As long as the general price level was low and stable (which is was in the 1920s) there was no reason to worry about anything else, such as the massive global asset, credit, growth bubbles being fueled by the Fed’s low interest rate policy (implemented to help the UK recovery from post WWI recession).   IT is a historical fact that the Fed kept interest rates artificially low in the 1920s behind which it fueled (what I would call) a massive “inflation” bubble which led directly to a stock market bubble / bust and then on to the Great Depression! 

The Austrian School focuses on the cause of the Depression in the policies leading up to it, not in the policy mistakes made after the credit/asset/ growth bubble burst.  The key focus of policy attention for the Austrians is avoiding the credit boom (which they consider inflation) in the first place.  once inflation shows up in the general price index it is too late!

Again according to the Austrian school, it wasn’t what we did after the Crash of 1929 that caused the Depression; it was the easy money policy we pursued ahead of it.  Now we have a central bank governor who is obsessed with avoiding the “mistakes” the Fed made AFTER the stock market crash in 1929 which he argues led to the Great Depression – i.e. keeping monetary policy too tight.   Yes, Bernanke seems to have avoided a repeat of the Great Depression with his QE1 and 2.  But that doesn’t mean he hasn’t sown the seeds for a Great Stagflation, which is what I believe he has done.  

Printing money may be enough to avoid a Great Depression redux, but we have no clue what the second round effects will be of the money printing done ostensibly to avoid a deflationary spiral.   Well we actually do have a clue that the second round effects will be:  we see them already, e.g. raging commodity price inflation.  What we still don’t know is how all of this will play out.  We don’t know how the exact narrative will play out in terms of what markets will be stressed to the breaking point.  but it will happen.   We are already seeing signs of stresses in Egypt with food prices fueling political instability.  We are seeing stresses I China and in many other parts of the world fueled by the global USD inflation facilitated by the Fed.  I didn’t know sub-prime would derail the US economy in 2007, (some smart analysts did identify sub prime as bubble market) but what I did know is that that we were in a boom / bust cycle thanks to the gold signal.

There is an old french proverb that says you find your destiny on the road you take to avoid it.  no matter what Bernanke does, the damage that was done to US economy and financial markets was done in the easy money policy leading up to the credit crisis of 2007/8.   Most Austrians focus on the easy money period of Greenspan’s Fed in fueling the housing bubble.  I focus on the second easy money period from 2005 and 2007 as a vital part of the story.  this second easy money period wasn’t caused by the Fed doing anything wrong per se, except to use the CPI as its inflation indicator. 

In my unique framework, the second inflation was caused by a massive adverse shock to money demand which led to massive liquidity bubble – on top of bubble already fueled by Greenspan.  But in my hypothesis, we wouldn’t have had the Great Recession of 2008 without the second big money inflation.  this part of my story is outside the Austrian School framework.  (it is no coincidence <Murphy doesn’t talk about the gold signal in his article.)

The gold signal told us we were in a global liquidity / credit / “inflation” (in classical sense) bubble was brewing in 2005-2007 while the fact that CPI remained low was used as an excuse to keep the good times rolling.  The IMF, Federal Reserve, World Bank and most mainstream economists were talking about how great the world economy very late into 2007.  Bernanke continued to claim sub prime was containable.  All because he had no context for appreciating the gold signal.

The return of commodity and gold price inflation tells us we are in the middle of another mini-cycle of what I believe will turn out to be a secular global liquidity super cycle.   When the bust happens the Fed will just keep printing money to reflate markets.  Each reflation cycle distorts the economy even more because liquidity is pumped into economy at zero interest rates and thus goes to projects it wouldn’t otherwise go to if not for the easy money underpinning the low interest rates.  Ultimately, that means stagflation of one sort or another.

The fix as I’ve said before is a trifecta of policy measures none of which seem remotely possible in the current political environment:

Sound money, entitlement reform and massive supply side de-regulation.

We are getting the exact opposite.  How can it end well?  Do we really believe the Federal Reserve can micro manage a soft landing for the economy via enlightened money printing? 

In 2005 to 2007, the gold price was screaming to us that we were in the middle of a massive credit / liquidity bubble.  but mainstream economics and mainstream monetary policy makers had no way to foresee a credit/liquidity/inflation bubble because they were erroneously fixated on CPI.   “We” continue to remain erroneously fixated on CPI!  It makes no sense.  We keep the CPI target because it is convenient.  No other target is consistent with having a Federal Reserve piggy bank that both the political right and left want to fund their big government priorities.  We don’t blame the CPI target for the boom / bust because we don’t want to face the painful tradeoffs that would come with a new sound money framework organized around a new inflation target, such as gold or a commodity basket.  So what we do is create a narrative that explains the bust in the proximate causes of the crisis and then we go around fixing the proximate causes with more “enlightened” big government interventions.  It is no coincidence the narrative explaining the Great Recession of 2008 is essentially the same narrative used to explain the Great Depression:  that these cycles were caused by greedy investment bankers, lax regulation, evil new financial products (margin lending in 1920s, derivatives today), assete bubbles.

What is clear to me is that the underlying cause of the Great Depression and the Great Recession of 2008 is easy money.  The perfect storm of proximate causes of both historical events could not have occurred without the Federal Reserve manipulating interest rates lower than they other wise would have been without the central bank.    

The 40% increase in the gold price since 2008 is telling us that we are right back where we started:  in the midst of a global inflation bubble facilitated with Fed policy QE1 QE2.    

the article copied below doesn't include charts. to view charts go to orginal article at:

Like Investors Finally Fear the Inflation Precipice on Facebook
Investors Finally Fear the Inflation Precipice
by Robert P. Murphy on February 10, 2011
Well it's about time. The headline on Monday's CNBC article announces: "Investors Starting to Believe That Inflation Threat is Real."
For some time, I have been a proud member of the fuddy duddies who have been predicting the return of serious stagflation. Thus far, our prognostications have clearly been half-right — the "real economy" is indeed caught in a terrible rut, far worse than most of the Keynesian economists recognized even in late 2008.
However, on the (price) inflation front, things are not as clear-cut. Although asset prices and producer prices have surged in response to Bernanke's monetary pumping, retail consumer prices (at least as officially reported by the Bureau of Labor Statistics) have not been rising at alarming rates.
I am not the first economist to explain this apparent anomaly by reference to Wile E. Coyote: The serious inflation won't hit until everyone thinks it is going to hit. And although the "fundamentals" of serious price inflation have been in place since late 2008, we are seeing more and more signs that Bernanke's dam of obfuscation is starting to crack.

A Simple Picture

Simplistic as it may seem, I still cannot shake the feeling that the below chart is all we really need to know that eventually, we will experience large price hikes:
Yes, yes, there are all sorts of sophisticated arguments for why there's nothing to see here, just keep moving along, the dollar will be fine. In particular, there are arguments about the demand for holding "base" money totally offsetting Bernanke's injections, and the huge increase in excess reserves means that the new money isn't "leaking out" into the broader economy.
However, when the serious price inflation comes — as I still believe it will — I think we will all look back at the above chart and be shocked that people were worried about deflation in 2008-2010. And there is precedent for this sort of thing; remember that in 2005 and 2006 plenty of really smart people (including Ben Bernanke) denied that there was a housing bubble[1]:

In Bernanke I Don't Trust

It is true that Bernanke could reverse course before things are too late, as far as the purchasing power of the dollar is concerned. But this would entail devastating pain to the banking sector, since the Fed would have to reverse the policies that bailed out the overleveraged titans in the first place. If Bernanke has to choose between saving rich bankers or the dollar, I am confident he will choose the former.
When Bernanke made his infamous appearance on 60 Minutes, most analysts understandably focused on his absurd claim that he wasn't printing money. But the thing that most alarmed me was this exchange (starting at about 7:20 in this video):
BERNANKE: There really is no problem with raising rates, tightening monetary policy, slowing the economy, reducing inflation at the appropriate time. …
Q: You have what degree of confidence in your ability to control this?
BERNANKE: A hundred percent.
Now that should be terrifying. Realistically, Bernanke shouldn't have 100 percent confidence that he can control his toaster. I mean, he might turn the dial up too high, or someone might spill water on it. It could happen.
By the same token, there are all sorts of scenarios where the natural "unwinding" of the Fed's extraordinary policies won't work as planned. In particular, if even official CPI inflation starts creeping above 4 and 5 percent on an annual basis, while unemployment remains above (say) 8 percent, then it will become apparent that Bernanke's "exit strategy" leads into a brick wall.

"Well, If the Fed Started Monetizing the Debt, Then I'd Worry About Inflation …"

One of the more absurd stances rejecting the inflationist warnings comes from people who think Federal Reserve policy is completely divorced from the Treasury's fiscal position. Such naïve analysts think that Bernanke's decision to soak up more than one trillion in government debt had nothing to do with the massive deficits that the government has been and will continue to run.
Those pooh-poohing our current situation will concede that interwar Germany or modern Zimbabwe got into trouble all right, but those were situations where the central bank "monetized the debt." This supposedly stands in sharp contrast to the scientific monetary policies of the "independent" Federal Reserve.
To put these claims in context, note that in the 2nd quarter of 2009, the Fed's absorption of Treasury debt amounted to 48 percent of the new debt issued in that period. And ZeroHedge posted the following chart showing that the Fed is currently the world's largest single holder of Treasury securities, surpassing China:

Conclusion

No one knows the future for certain. But given the economic and political realities, I still remain confident that prices quoted in US dollars will continue to escalate, not only in commodities and certain asset classes, but eventually in most consumer goods. At some point it will be so obvious that not even Ben Bernanke will be able to deny it.
When will the breakout occur? Again, no one can know such things for sure, but there are growing signs that "the market" will soon recognize that Bernanke & Co. have painted us into a very tight corner.


Robert Murphy is an adjunct scholar of the Mises Institute, where he will be teaching Anatomy of the Fed at the Mises Academy this winter. He runs the blog Free Advice and is the author of The Politically Incorrect Guide to Capitalism, the Study Guide to Man, Economy, and State with Power and Market, the Human Action Study Guide, The Politically Incorrect Guide to the Great Depression and the New Deal, and his newest book, Lessons for the Young Economist. Send him mail. See Robert P. Murphy's article archives.
Comment on the blog.
You can subscribe to future articles by Robert P. Murphy via this RSS feed.
Notes
[1] To my eternal shame, I was one of those (hopefully) smart economists who overlooked the dangers for far too long. So when I say that people can latch on to arguments to dismiss warnings, and later wonder what in the world they were thinking, I speak from personal experience.

Tuesday, February 1, 2011

QE2 Epitomizes Moral Bankruptcy of the Big Government Center

"The Federal Reserve has surpassed China as the leading holder of US Treasury securities even though it has yet to reach the halfway mark in its latest round of quantitative easing, according to official figures."  full article copied below.


This cannot end well.   First principles tells us so.  Common sense screams it. 

Ben Franklin warned that:
They who can give up essential liberty to obtain a little temporary safety, deserve neither liberty nor safety.*

Central banking epitomizes this fateful trade.  Central banking promises safety yet it requires we give up the liberty inherent in sound money systems.  Central banking is antithetical to sound money.  

The Fed was established in 1913 ostensibly to help prevent the recurrence of Panics, like the Panic of 1907.  We traded liberty for safety.  And what happened?  The Fed fueled a massive credit bubble in the US and global economy in the 1920s which led directly to the Crash of 1929 and the Great Depression.

We traded Panics for a Great Depression. 

The mainstream narrative for the Great Depression blames too little government for the Great Depression.  It blames the Fed for not being pro-active enough following the Crash of 1929.

Policy makers (including Bernanke) spent the last generation working diligently promising that they would never let another Great Depression happen.  We learned our lessons.  The result of lessons learned is QE2.  

The problem with the conventional wisdom of what caused the Great Depression is that it doesn't take into account what are the unintended consequences of active Fed intervention.  Sure, the Fed may be able to prevent a Great Depression with active monetary interventions.  But, then what?

What comes next?  What happens when the Fed does intervene to prevent the next Great Depression.

This is exactly the experiment which policy makers have thrust us into. 

The Austrian School of economics looks for the causes of a historic Crash (like the Great Depression or Great Recession of 2008) not in policy errors after the credit / asset bubble bursts, but rather in the policies that fueled the credit bubble in the first place.

We will learn a very painful lesson from QE1 and QE2.  We will learn that the Fed can stop a Great Depression, but it can't stop a bunch of other unintended consequences that will play out in some other constellation of crises that will be called something else.   Maybe it will be called the Great Unravelling or the Great Malaise or the Great Volatility. 

We'll look back at the "mistakes" and again promise:  never again.

What we should promise is never to believe the promises of policy makers.

Bernanke promised on 60 minutes with 100%certainty that the Fed had the tools to unwind its purchases of US Treasuries.  This is the same enlightened policy maker who promised that the sub prime crisis was containable.   Until it wasn't.

Shame me once shame on you, shame me twice shame on me.

What we should promise is to hold fast to our commitment to liberty no matter what storms are raging.  

If we believe in the sanctity of liberty; if we believe in the sanctity of limited government and of private property, then we cannot but  believe the Fed's QE2 experiment will end in anything but economic impoverishment, especially for the most economically vulnerable -- those who Big Government promises to be looking out for first and foremost.

The New Center is a political space where liberty is an absolute concept, not a relative concept.  Liberty is not to be traded casually -- or even with great thoughtfulness -- for temporary safety. 

Liberty is the north star of the New Center politics.  Don't trade if for any gold plated promises by politicians who promise the moon.

the Fed in general and QE2 in particular is the opposite of liberty.  the Fed and QE2 are the epitome of the Big Government trade that promises safety if you just give up a "little" liberty. 

giving up a little liberty is a slippery slope.  we have seen it over and over and over again throughout history.  Federal income taxes were established in 1913 with the highest rate set at 7%.   by the 1960s the top rate was over 90%.  it is also possible to claw back liberty -- the top marginal rate is well below its historical highs.  But we are headed for higher taxes again.  Giving up a little liberty is begging for a losing, Sisyphean battle.   

Central banking in general and the Fed in particular is tyranny personified and justified by upside down, ends justify the means morality.    In what kind of ethical world do the ends justify the means?  It is the world of the Big Government Center that promises good results -- no matter the methods employed.  Don't worry look behind the curtain ...  everything is fine .... we have everything under control.

Bernanke literally is the embodiment of the Wizard in the Wizard of Oz.  he is all powerful in his own mind, but completely powerless in the real world.

It is not all doom and gloom.  The future is bright.  But, the hand wringing and finger pointing and the economic stagnation will continue in America until we stop looking to government for answers and hold government responsible for one thing:  protecting individual liberty and freedom.  

That means sound money and limited government.  It means rule by law and principle, not rule by good intentions and arbitrary whim of enlightened policy makers. 

Sound money and limited government are one and the same.  That is the only way to a bright future.  Not a perfect future.

*Note from Wikiquote: This quote was written by Franklin, with quotation marks but almost certainly his original thought, sometime shortly before February 17, 1775 as part of his notes for a proposition at the Pennsylvania Assembly, as published in Memoirs of the life and writings of Benjamin Franklin 

Fed passes China in Treasury holdings
By Michael Mackenzie in New York
Published: February 2 2011 00:01 | Last updated: February 2 2011 00:01
The Federal Reserve has surpassed China as the leading holder of US Treasury securities even though it has yet to reach the halfway mark in its latest round of quantitative easing, according to official figures.
Based on weekly data released on Thursday, the New York Fed’s holdings of Treasuries in its System Open Market Account, known as Soma, total $1,108bn, made up of bills, notes, bonds and Treasury Inflation Protected Securities, or Tips.

According to the most recent US Treasury data on foreign holders of US government paper, China holds $896bn and Japan owns $877bn.

“By June [the Fed] will have accumulated some $1,600bn of Treasury securities, likely to be in the vicinity of China and Japan’s combined holdings,” said Richard Gilhooly, a strategist at TD Securities. “The New York Fed surpassed China in the past month as the largest holder of US Treasury securities,” he noted.
The Fed is buying Treasury debt under two programmes. The largest is QE2, which began in November and is scheduled to involve $600bn of purchases by June.

It is also buying $30bn of Treasuries a month as it reinvests principal payments from its large holdings of mortgage debt and debt issued by government housing agencies – a programme dubbed QE lite.
By the end of June, the Fed plans to buy $800bn in Treasury debt under both programmes. Since November, the Fed has purchased $284bn of Treasuries.

The Fed has devoted 67 per cent of its QE2 purchases to Treasuries with a maturity of four-and-a-half to 10 years. That has helped pull back yields in that part of the yield curve from their highs of December.
By contrast, just 5 per cent of the Fed’s buying has been for Treasury debt longer than 17 years. Last Friday, the yield on 30-year bonds briefly rose to its highest level since last April.

“The end of QE2 will be a big test as rates are likely to rise once the Fed stops buying large amounts of Treasuries,” said David Ader, a strategist at CRT Capital. “We don’t know if that means a rise of 20, 30 or even 50 basis points for key yields.”

In total, foreign central banks hold $2,604bn of Treasuries, according to the Fed. After rising from $2,250bn at the end of last June, foreign central banks have stayed at about $2,600bn since mid-November, when the Fed began QE2. This indicates the Fed has stepped up as other central banks have scaled back their Treasuries purchases.

Before the financial crisis, the Fed held $775bn of Treasuries in Soma. That was reduced by $300bn during the first half of 2008, when the Fed sold Treasuries and focused on supporting the financial system. The first QE program, which began in 2009, saw the Fed buy $300bn of Treasuries.

Public Choice vs Public Interest Theory

Are good intentions enough to justify public policy?  check out this article … it is fascinating explanation of the difference between ‘public choice theory’ and ‘public interest theory’.  after reading this article, public interest theory seems so incredibly naïve and utopian, yet I think this is exactly the premise that underlies the modern progressive world view of team Obama.

Andrew P. Morriss

Law and Good Intentions

Ends don't justify means.

June 2005 • Volume: 55 • Issue: 5 • Print This Post1 comment
Americans, not just classical-liberal ones, have an almost instinctual distrust of government. Our nation began in a revolt inspired partly by the “Intolerable Acts” of King George III and taxation without representation. The Declaration of Independence recited a lengthy list of grievances against the British government, summarized as “a history of repeated injuries and usurpations, all having in direct object the establishment of an absolute Tyranny over these States.”
This instinct, which often mystifies our foreign friends despite their own experiences with tyrannies, is put on a solid theoretical footing by Public Choice theory, pioneered by James Buchanan and Gordon Tullock in The Calculus of Consent in 1962 and developed thereafter by an ever-growing number of scholars.

Public Choice explains why governments favor special interests. Providing benefits to a small group at the expense of the diffuse majority seems like such an obvious course of action once one has read Buchanan and Tullock that it is hard today to grasp just how revolutionary their theory was when it appeared.
Yet The Calculus of Consent was a revolutionary document, as revolutionary in its way as the Declaration not quite 200 years earlier. When the book was published, the reigning theory of government (one still taught in many high schools and even some colleges) was the “public interest” theory. Under this theory each legislator is motivated to serve the interest of the public at large. If pollution is the problem to be addressed, then the legislature seeks to minimize the total costs of both reducing pollution and pollution itself by choosing the least costly methods and the most appropriate regulatory measures to do so. Statutes and regulations are not intended to advantage particular industries or regions at the expense of others, but to benefit all.
Despite Americans’ skepticism about government, they continue to have a great deal of faith in some aspects of it. Polling data consistently support the contradictory conclusion that although Americans do not believe the government is looking out for the public interest and correctly identify a variety of special interests as benefiting from regulations, they also think well of their own representatives and of the local governments with which they have more direct experience. General questions about trust in government find most people are skeptical quasi-libertarians. Questions about specific regulatory policies often find the opposite, however, with majorities in favor of government action. In short, the American attitude is something like: “They’re all crooks except for my guy—he’s looking out for me” and “Special interests control the government except for the environment, labor protection, workplace safety, and so on.”
This seeming paradox is present in many people’s reaction to Public Choice analysis: “Yes, but what about the good intentions of the really dedicated public servants?” While recognizing that particular accounts of the dispensation of special favors are true, nonclassical liberals often react to attempts to generalize from those case studies by accusing classical liberals of being “cynical.” We classical liberals can protest until our faces turn blue that Public Choice does account for good old Congressman Smith and Bureaucrat Jones, who really are selflessly dedicated to the public good. Smith and Jones have to keep their jobs to exercise their selflessness, and keeping their jobs means getting re-elected and maintaining (or increasing) their agency budgets. After all, if Smith loses his seat and Jones her job at EPA, neither will be able to be selfless on behalf of the rest of us. Competing for resources in the political arena requires even those with good intentions to get down in the trenches—seeking votes and campaign contributions, for example—and trench warfare requires allies. Sometimes those allies come with a price, such as a minor tweak to rules or legislation that helps a particular interest group. Such compromises, which are absolutely necessary to maintaining an agency or a seat in Congress, are inevitable and offer special interests the opportunity to influence even the best-intentioned public servant.
Unfortunately, I rarely find that this answer persuades those convinced of Congressman Smith’s and Bureaucrat Jones’s dedication to the public. Smith and Jones have such good intentions that no list of counterexamples will persuade some folks to not fall back on a public-interest explanation from time to time. How then should we address the question of the good intentions of our public servants?

A recent visit to Guatemala gave me some new answers to the problem of good intentions. I have spent several months over the past few years teaching at Universidad Francisco Marroquin, a free-market university in Guatemala City, and traveling around Guatemala. Unlike Americans, Guatemalans do not have many illusions about government. Having experienced a brutal civil war for several decades, military dictatorships (including some headed by generals of questionable sanity), and endemic corruption, Guatemalans with whom I have talked go well beyond Public Choice theory’s “getting re-elected means I need to compromise my principles to gain votes and campaign contributions” explanation for how the well-intentioned politician might serve special interests. (Although my impressions of Guatemalan public opinion are not based on scientific surveys, they are based on talking with many students and faculty, as well as individuals outside the university.)
Guatemalans largely believe their politicians are thieves—with considerable justification. Members of the last government, for example, appear to have stolen on a scale that even legendary Chicago machine politicians would admire: the former tax administrator is accused of stealing more than 62 million quetzales (approximately $8 million); millions more vanished from the social security trust fund; and the former president fled the country. These are but a few of the scandals since the last election. Not surprisingly, besides believing that government is generally corrupt, many Guatemalans also believe that almost any particular politician is corrupt as well.

Despite this history of corruption, three programs of recent Guatemalan governments are examples of good-intentioned policies, and few people tell special-interest stories about them. Yet all three have failed spectacularly. Their failures provide at least a partial answer to the question of how to understand why even good intentions are not enough to justify government action.

Traffic-Safety Mimes

Because unemployment is high, many street corners in Guatemala City feature individuals hustling to earn money by entertaining drivers stuck at traffic lights. Clowns, acrobats, and mimes of various skill levels perform and then walk down the line of cars asking for contributions. Far less obnoxious than the “window cleaners” who used to plague New York City drivers, some of these individuals are genuinely entertaining, while others are simply sad.
To promote the use of seat belts, the Guatemala City municipal government hired 20 street mimes in April 2001. They approached cars and when an occupant was seen not wearing a seat belt, they mimed buckling up. The program’s intent was only the best: Guatemala City traffic is alarmingly chaotic, with frequent accidents. Seat-belt usage is clearly lower than it ought to be, particularly given the driving habits. Buckling up is a low-cost way to save lives—by any measure, encouraging more people to use seat belts voluntarily would improve Guatemala.

Moreover, hiring a few street mimes can hardly be seen as a special-interest program, and it would cost relatively little. (Admittedly, the program benefited the mimes, who no longer depended on tips, and insurance companies, which might pay out less in injury awards if more people used seat belts.) If we concede that this was an attempt to serve the public interest, we are left with the puzzle that the program was unpopular and abandoned after only a few months. Why?
Most people with whom I spoke about the program said it was unpopular because people found it annoying to be hectored by strangers. Drivers did not like the well-intentioned advice to buckle up being personally directed at them by a mime. Government failed not because it delivered a windfall to street mimes, but because the idea of a nanny state is unattractive when it is personalized. Guatemalans do not want the government to station people on street corners to lecture them (even silently) on appropriate behavior—even behavior that is virtually costless and has large benefits. People tolerate things like the increasingly strident warning labels on cigarette packages because we can ignore them if we choose. But put a mime just inches from our faces, buckling his imaginary seat belt, and people rebel because the nanny is impossible to ignore. Good intentions aren’t enough.

Teaching Literacy

Guatemala has an enormous literacy problem. Many of its people speak only one of the 23 indigenous languages (and an even larger number of dialects) rather than Spanish, and even more cannot read and write Spanish or any indigenous language. (The official literacy rate is only 71 percent.) Unless Guatemala solves this problem, its economic future is bleak. Promoting Spanish literacy is critical and clearly in the public interest, however defined.
To do so, the education ministry in December 2000 decreed that every Guatemalan high-school student would have to teach someone to read and write in Spanish. The aim was noble. And although the means chosen were questionable (are high-school students really equipped to teach literacy? By what right does the state conscript labor even for noble purposes?), the program hardly benefited a special interest. If anything, for-profit Spanish teachers were disadvantaged by the competing flood of conscript labor. Nonetheless after three years the program was discontinued.
Again, let us concede that this was a genuine attempt to advance some public interest. Why did it fail? One important reason was the predictable result of making something valuable (a high-school diploma) depend on the cooperation of someone other than the student, in this case the illiterate. The illiterate cannot read and write, but they understand incentives. Quickly realizing that they had something valuable (their teachable status), the illiterate (who, of course, were mostly poor as a result of their illiteracy) began charging the high-school students to give them lessons. Paid by the lesson, the illiterate lacked any incentive to succeed in learning to read—indeed, the slower people learned, the more lessons they could charge the students to give to them. Good intentions were not enough to overcome the bad incentives created by this program. Eventually, the stories about the need for high-school students to pay the illiterate to learn led to the program’s downfall.

Protecting Forests

Guatemala is a lush, green country. The central highlands have extensive forests. The jungle in the northern region stretches as far as the eye can see. Seeking to protect its forest resources, the Guatemalan government restricts logging. In particular, because of extensive deforestation in the department of Totonicaban, the government in the 1990s decreed that landowners must pay the government a fee and agree to plant five new trees to gain permission to cut down a tree on their own land. (The fee varied with the size of the tree cut down.) Being sensible (and this is the good-intentioned part), the government left an exception for cutting down trees infected with the gusano peludo, or “hairy worm.” That pest had infected large areas of the department, and the only remedy was to remove the trees. This is the weakest of my public-interest examples because there is abundant evidence that government land-management policies are driven by interest-group pressures. Let us nonetheless concede for purposes of argument that this was a good-faith effort to protect the environment.
Not too surprisingly, people who wanted to cut down trees determined that infecting them with the worm, easily done by placing infected pine cones near healthy trees, avoided the fee and the need for replacements. After this decree was issued the number of infected trees skyrocketed. The policy failed to protect Guatemala’s forests, even harming them as the infected area spread to provide an excuse for timber harvests. The reason is simple: Something valuable was available only if it first was infected. Not taking account of the economic incentives created by the well-intentioned rule doomed it to failure.
My three examples of good intentions gone bad are not, of course, a formal proof that they will never produce a successful government program. They do illustrate the perils of relying on good intentions alone, however. The street-mime program failed because the Guatemala City government did not consider how drivers would react to being personally nagged. Spending someone else’s money, the city government had little incentive to do market research on the effective means of increasing seat-belt use and, with the best of intentions, did not accomplish its goal. The literacy program and forestry law addressed serious problems, but failed to consider the obvious economic incentives created by the programs’ structures.
Street mimes teaching seat-belt use are good for a chuckle, but the point is not that governments do silly things from time to time. The point is that good intentions are not enough.

Book Recommendation: Rollback by Thomas Woods, Jr

Wow!
check this out....according to the Mises.org description of this brand new book by Thomas Woods ....

"Woods shows how the conventional conservative and liberal solutions fall far short of the mark. He argues here for a wholesale gutting of the state, using massive amounts of data and arguments."

This is exactly what I am arguing here at Mister Center blog:  i.e. big government policy orientations have infected (hijacked?) both the political liberal/progressive left AND the conservative right. 

Lets go back to the political CENTER where America was founded:  on the principles of liberty and limited government.

Woods addresses a huge range of topics in his book that include self destructive, Big government ideas from both the left and the right.  Big government is not just a scourge on the left. 

The wide range of well intended policy prescriptions included in Woods' book include those related to unemployment, health care, social security, the Fed, regulation of business, the drug war, military build up, labor regulations, government spending, debt, protectionism, and much more. 

Notice that this list includes priorities of  both the left (e.g. labor regulations, universal health care) and the right (e.g. military build up, drug war) and bipartisan priorities of what I would call the big government center (government spending, the Fed, social security).

In each case, Woods lays out the terrible results of government policy and the prosperity-creating advantages of rolling back every aspect of each.

I've copied below the full book description from the Mises website.  If you don't have time to read the book, then by all means read this description.

Book Description 
For many decades, the advocates of freedom have pointed to the myriad of ways in which government wrecks society. In this wonderfully well-timed book, Thomas Woods provides the rationale and the road map for taking seriously the ideas of liberty.

This is NOT just another policy tract. This book is filled with surprises about how the government wrecks our lives in unexpected ways. And Woods shows how the conventional conservative and liberal solutions fall far short of the mark. He argues here for a wholesale gutting of the state, using massive amounts of data and arguments.

With a particular focus on the Obama administration's priorities, Woods shows how and why it is time to reverse directions completely: from more government toward a radical unraveling of government intervention. The time is ripe for just such a message.

Woods addresses a huge range of topics here: unemployment, health care, social security, the Fed, regulation of business, the drug war, military build up, labor regulations, government spending, debt, protectionism, and much more.

In each case, he lays out the terrible results of government policy and the prosperity-creating advantages of rolling back every aspect of each.

There are several beautiful aspects to Woods's book. First, the accumulation of data to support the case is extremely useful to anyone who makes a case for freedom. Second, the book puts between two covers information that one might otherwise have to hunt for days to find. Third, the book is beautifully written so that it inspires both radical understanding and action.

As Woods makes clear, this debate is not merely abstract and intellectual. Woods warns that on the present road, the U.S. could find itself in an economic debacle that makes 2008 seem like a mere warm up. He demonstrates the complete inviability of the outrageous spending, the money printing, and debts as far as the eye can see.

Here is a manual for action that is essential for every lover of liberty. Reviewers from Ron Paul to Jeffrey Miron agree that Rollback is the best case yet in print for dismantling the state as we know it.



RollbackOther products by Woods, Thomas E. Jr.
reviews

Item #: B1001
Part #: 9781596981416
Reg. Price: $27.95 USD
Our Price: $19.00 USD
Quantity:
More
Less

A Modest Proposal on Education

We take for granted the logic of the separation of church and state.  And for good reason.  We see the problems caused when the state and church are comingled as is the case in many Islamic countries. 

Why not a separation of state and education?

Why should "education" be the purview of the Federal government? 

Bitter debates such as those over whether our schools should teach creationism or Darwinian evolution (or both) wouldn't be an issue if the government wasn't in the business of managing public school education curriculums. 

Again, I would like to recommend the Book State and Education>
Education and the State

buy it here:
http://mises.org/store/Education-and-the-State-P10423.aspx

Education and the State first appeared in 1965 and was immediately hailed as one of the century's most important works on education. In the thirty years that have followed, the questions this book raised concerning state-run education have grown immeasurably in urgency and intensity. Education and the State re-examines the role of government in education and challenges the fundamental statist assumption that the state is best able to provide an education for the general population.

West explores the views on education of the nineteenth-century British reformers and classical economists who argued for state education. He demonstrates that by the Foster Act of 1870 the state system of education was superimposed upon successful private efforts, thereby suppressing an emerging and increasingly robust structure of private, voluntary, and competitive education funded by families, churches, and philanthropies.

Gotta Love Those Teacher Unions!

The fact that NYC requires a "secret" plan to fire "useless" teachers is a tragedy.   Governor Christie has stared down teachers unions somewhat successfully in NJ.  But, any effort to deal with public unions is an uphill climb. 
 
A much more fundamental solution to the union problem in public education is to get the state out of managing a public education system in the first place.
 
Note that the Transportation Safety Administration is mobilizing to unionize!  this is soooo predictable. 
 
Government solutions to public policy challenges sound good on paper, but once they are implemented, these solutions (by definition) are subject to being hijacked by special interests, such as public unions in the case of public education.  
 
Read the article copied below and weep.  
 
ps...
The same dynamic plays out in all of the other sectors where the government "takes over".  Even if the government doesn't "take over" explicitly as is the case with public education, the sectors where the government involves itself with subsidies also fall prey to the same dynamics:    i.e. regulatory capture, union capture, special interest capture.    Consider the housing sector, health care sector, finance and banking, green energy -- special interest capture has been the name of the game in all of these sectors thanks to well intended government subsidies. 
 
bottom line:  Big Government sows the seeds of its own self destructive dynamics. 
 
 
Updated: Mon., Jan. 31, 2011, 12:36 PM home

Secret plan to ax useless teachers

Last Updated: 12:36 PM, January 31, 2011
Posted: 1:30 AM, January 31, 2011
State lawmakers are secretly eyeing a compromise that would allow Mayor Bloomberg to fire thousands of "nonteaching teachers" without consideration of the "last in, first out" law, The Post has learned.
The plan, being discussed at the highest levels of the Legislature and with aides to Bloomberg, would grant the mayor the right to fire between 2,000 to 4,000 nonclassroom teachers -- including all those who formerly languished in the notorious "rubber room" under disciplinary charges.

The plan would also target members of the "absent teacher reserve pool" -- which includes nonworking but on-the-payroll teachers from schools that have been shut down because of poor performance -- and teachers assigned only to "administrative functions," sources said.

Bloomberg warned Friday that the city might be forced to lay off as many as 20,000 teachers because of a combination of a city revenue shortfall and the severe state budget cuts to be unveiled tomorrow by Gov. Cuomo. If the plan becomes reality, about 10 to 20 percent of teachers slated for layoffs simply because they were hired last would be spared.

Bloomberg, conceding that significant teacher cuts are inevitable, has launched an aggressive campaign to overturn the state law that requires the city to fire teachers on the basis of seniority and not competence.
State lawmakers privately say Bloomberg can't win full repeal of the law because of intense union opposition and concerns over the criteria the mayor would use to justify teacher dismissals.
But the dismissal of poorly performing "nonteaching teachers" was described by a top state official as "potentially doable."
Cuomo and Senate Republicans have signaled they're open to such a measure, but Assembly Speaker Sheldon Silver (D-Manhattan) and his union-funded Democratic Conference have yet to weigh in.
Meanwhile, Bloomberg lambasted the current rules in a speech at the Christian Cultural Center in Brooklyn yesterday and demanded that Albany take action.
"I say enough with Albany rules. You just cannot do this. If the governor's budget contains education cuts, it must also contain changes to the law so that we can take merit into account when making these difficult decisions. It must allow us to keep our best teachers," he said.
He warned it was "conceivable" the city would have to lay off "nearly every teacher hired in the last five years -- the ones who are the very future of our school system. This is serious."
Laying off the 20,000 newest teachers would hit poorest neighborhoods hardest, because schools in those areas tend to have the freshest faces on the job.
"Albany rules say that when it comes to teaching, talent doesn't matter, results don't matter. The only thing that matters is how long you've been in the system," Bloomberg said.
"We've worked too hard these last years to improve our schools, and I can just tell you I will be out there fighting with every breath I have to make sure we can keep that progress going, because teachers really have been at the heart of that progress."
*
Cuomo will get a surprise wet kiss from the Senate GOP today -- bolstering his strength with the Legislature a day before he unveils his tough new budget plan firing thousands of workers and cutting $10 billion in projected spending.
Senate Majority Leader Dean Skelos (R-LI) plans to pass the governor's controversial proposed 2 percent cap on most local and school property taxes outside New York City, a popular proposal with voters, but one that is bitterly opposed by public-employee unions and cash-poor local governments.
Passage of the cap, which was quietly introduced in the Senate at 11 p.m. Friday so that it could "age" for approval today, will give Cuomo a major political boost just hours before his public approval is likely to take a beating because of his austere budget plans.
*
The hottest question around the mahogany-lined walls of the Senate these days is: "Which Democrat is wearing a wire?"
The paranoia over a possible criminal probe -- always an undercurrent around a Legislature that has seen several members indicted in recent years -- is peaking amid a federal investigation of the AEG-Aqueduct bid-rigging scandal to which key Democratic leaders were linked in a bombshell inspector general's report last fall.
Also fueling the paranoia are probes of pork-barrel member items distributed by outer-borough Democrats, and, the widespread question goes, who knows what else?
Additional reporting by Sally Goldenberg
fredric.dicker@nypost.com

Obama's Spuknik moment doesn't fly

Jonah Goldberg hits the nail on the head here on so many levels in his article "Obama's Spuknik Moment Doesn't Fly."  This is a wonderful article.  I've copied it below.

The section on education ties in to my previous post.  Goldberg says:

"Meanwhile, thanks partly to Sputnik, our educational system became more federalized, centralized and bureaucratized. I must have missed the news reports on how this transformation wildly improved the quality of American education over the past half-century."

The whole notion of countries competing against each other to "win the future" smuggles in the premise that someone (the government) needs to be in charge of leading the effort. 

And that in a nut shell is the "progressive / liberal" world view.  This premise also happens to play a big role in the world view of Big government conservatives, such as the neo-cons, who argued for Iraq War as a way for America to re-shape the Middle East.   


OBama's Spuknik Moment Doesn't Fly
 
It's a sign of how tinny and uninspiring President Obama's State of the Union address was that a week later it all seems so forgettable.
Let's see, there was something about high-speed rail and a lot more spending ("investing," in Washington-speak). There was the theme, "Winning the Future" a term that apparently focus-grouped so well that nobody in the White House bothered to look up the fact that Newt Gingrich has written a book by the same title and all but copyrighted the buzz-phrase.
And then there was all that stuff about Sputnik.
The president insisted, as he has done before, that this is "our generation's Sputnik moment" where we must galvanize the whole society with common purpose (he left unclear what this means for those still-living Americans whose generation's "Sputnik moment" was, well, Sputnik. Maybe they can sit this one out).
 
China is hardly the leader in technical, scientific, intellectual or artistic innovation.

Indeed, to hear Obama tell it, he has sounded the warning bell. We must lay down our proverbial shovels and hoes and run in from the fields to take our instruction from President Obama on how to deal with the current crisis.

Which crisis is that? You might think that he was referring to the fact that the country is flooding with red ink (according to the Congressional Budget Office, this will be our third consecutive year with a deficit above $1 trillion), and that everyone needs to help bail out the USS America before she capsizes. You might think his calls for unity might have something to do with the fact that we're fighting two wars and are under the constant threat of Islamic terrorism.

But, no. Apparently, our Sputnik moment requires that we launch an updated arms race with China, but instead of bombs and tanks, we must build windmills and brew the government moonshine we call ethanol.

Why the focus on China?
No metaphor can withstand too much scrutiny. But Obama's effort to recast America's plight as a replay of the last Sputnik moment fails in every intended regard.

According to Obama, China is eating our lunch at conservation and the all-important green energy business, where all the new good jobs will come from in the 21st century. He said during the State of the Union that China has built the world's biggest solar energy research facility (apparently, when it comes to solar research, size is everything). Therefore, America needs to revive what many liberals have long claimed was the Cold War hysteria that fueled the first space race, after the Soviets stunned America by launching the utterly useless satellite called "Sputnik."

Unfortunately, a great deal of this is simply nonsense. For starters, America is vastly more energy efficient than China and has been getting better at it for years. Since the oil shock of 1973, America's economy has nearly tripled and the population has more than doubled but we only use about 20% more oil than we did then. Meanwhile, China--thanks largely to its insatiable appetite for coal--is far less green. In 2006, according to the Heritage Foundation, China and America had generally the same greenhouse emissions, by 2009 China's were 50% greater.

Ironically, China achieves abysmal numbers like these precisely because it pursues the sorts of policies Obama says we need more of: bureaucratic micromanagement, costly subsidies, arbitrary timetables, political goals that are unrelated to the market and unhinged from the science. China is hardly the leader in technical, scientific, intellectual or artistic innovation. That's where we're still No. 1 and that's why authoritarian China is trying to copy our economic model as best it can without adopting our political system. Think of it this way: Would a government agency have come up with the iPhone?

Our education failures
But Obama might say all that misses the point, because the Sputnik analogy applies with equal force to the need to revamp our educational system the way we did in the wake of Sputnik. But wait a second. It should go without saying that the NASA engineers who responded to Sputnik with the Apollo program were products of the pre-Sputnik educational system. And, as a matter of fact, those engineers were utterly unimpressed with the Soviets' accomplishment. (We could have launched a satellite much earlier, but we wanted the Soviets to go first so they would establish the right to launch satellites over other nations.)
Meanwhile, thanks partly to Sputnik, our educational system became more federalized, centralized and bureaucratized. I must have missed the news reports on how this transformation wildly improved the quality of American education over the past half-century.

Ironically, there's one way in which the Sputnik analogy is perfectly apt: It encapsulates how Obama thinks things are supposed to be done. The government tells the people what to do, and it relies on a handful of experts to get it done according to government specifications. And if conviction won't persuade Americans to spend their money on such enterprises, well, a little Red Scare might just do the trick.
Jonah Goldberg is a visiting fellow at the AEI.